[Congressional Bills 118th Congress]
[From the U.S. Government Publishing Office]
[S. 4308 Introduced in Senate (IS)]

<DOC>






118th CONGRESS
  2d Session
                                S. 4308

   To reform the antitrust laws to better protect competition in the 
 American economy, to amend the Clayton Act to modify the standard for 
an unlawful acquisition, to deter anticompetitive exclusionary conduct 
  that harms competition and consumers, to enhance the ability of the 
 Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission to enforce the 
                antitrust laws, and for other purposes.


_______________________________________________________________________


                   IN THE SENATE OF THE UNITED STATES

                              May 9, 2024

Ms. Klobuchar (for herself, Mr. Blumenthal, Mr. Whitehouse, Ms. Hirono, 
Mr. Booker, Mr. Welch, Mr. Warner, Mr. Wyden, Mr. Heinrich, Mr. Markey, 
  Mr. Schatz, and Ms. Smith) introduced the following bill; which was 
       read twice and referred to the Committee on the Judiciary

_______________________________________________________________________

                                 A BILL


 
   To reform the antitrust laws to better protect competition in the 
 American economy, to amend the Clayton Act to modify the standard for 
an unlawful acquisition, to deter anticompetitive exclusionary conduct 
  that harms competition and consumers, to enhance the ability of the 
 Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission to enforce the 
                antitrust laws, and for other purposes.

    Be it enacted by the Senate and House of Representatives of the 
United States of America in Congress assembled,

SECTION 1. SHORT TITLE.

    This Act may be cited as the ``Competition and Antitrust Law 
Enforcement Reform Act of 2024''.

SEC. 2. FINDINGS AND PURPOSES.

    (a) Findings.--Congress finds that--
            (1) competitive markets, in which multiple firms compete to 
        buy and sell products and services, are critical to ensuring 
        economic opportunity for all people in the United States and 
        providing resilience to the economy during unpredictable times;
            (2) when companies compete, businesses offer the highest 
        quality and choice of goods and services for the lowest 
        possible prices to consumers and other businesses;
            (3) competition fosters small business growth, reduces 
        economic inequality, and spurs innovation and job creation;
            (4) competitive markets are crucial for the United States 
        global economic competitiveness and national security;
            (5) in the United States economy today, the presence and 
        exercise of market power is substantial and growing;
            (6) the presence and exercise of market power makes it more 
        difficult for people in the United States to start their own 
        businesses, depresses wages, and increases economic inequality, 
        with particularly damaging effects on historically 
        disadvantaged communities;
            (7) market power and undue market concentration contribute 
        to the consolidation of political power, undermining the health 
        of democracy in the United States;
            (8) the anticompetitive effects of monopoly power or buyer 
        market power include higher prices, lower quality, lessened 
        choice, reduced innovation, foreclosure of competitors, and 
        increased entry barriers;
            (9) monopsony power or seller market power allows a firm to 
        force suppliers of goods or services to accept below market 
        prices or to force workers to accept below market wages, 
        resulting in lower quality products and services, reduced 
        opportunities for suppliers and workers, reduced availability 
        of products and services for consumers, reduced innovation, 
        foreclosure of competitors, and increased entry barriers;
            (10) horizontal consolidation, vertical consolidation, and 
        conglomerate mergers all have the potential to increase market 
        power and cause anticompetitive harm;
            (11) extensive consolidation is reducing competition and 
        threatens to place the American dream further out of reach for 
        many consumers in the United States;
            (12) since 2008, firms in the United States have engaged in 
        over $10,000,000,000,000 in mergers and acquisitions;
            (13) the acquisition of nascent or potential rivals by 
        dominant firms can present significant long-term threats to 
        competition and innovation and harm the global economic 
        competitiveness of the United States;
            (14) the acquisition, by one of its competitors, of a 
        maverick firm that plays a disruptive role in the market, by 
        using an innovative business model or technology, offering 
        lower prices or new, different products or services products, 
        or by other means that benefit consumers, often presents a 
        threat to competition;
            (15) section 7 of the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. 18) is the 
        primary line of defense against anticompetitive mergers;
            (16) in recent years, some court decisions and enforcement 
        policies have limited the vitality of the Clayton Act to 
        prevent harmful consolidation by--
                    (A) discounting previously accepted presumptions 
                that certain acquisitions are anticompetitive;
                    (B) focusing inordinately on the effect of an 
                acquisition on price in the short term, to the 
                exclusion of other potential anticompetitive effects;
                    (C) underestimating the dangers that horizontal, 
                vertical, and conglomerate mergers will lower quality, 
                reduce choice, impede innovation, exclude competitors, 
                increase entry barriers, or create buyer power, 
                including monopsony power;
                    (D) failing to properly account for direct evidence 
                of competitive harm, including intent evidence; and
                    (E) requiring the government to prove harmful 
                effects of a proposed merger to a near certainty;
            (17) anticompetitive exclusionary conduct constitutes a 
        particularly harmful exercise of market power and a substantial 
        threat to the United States economy;
            (18) when dominant sellers exercise market power, they harm 
        buyers by overcharging them, reducing product or service 
        quality, limiting their choices, and impairing innovation;
            (19) when dominant buyers exercise market power, they harm 
        suppliers by underpaying them, limiting their business 
        opportunities, and impairing innovation;
            (20) when dominant employers exercise market power, they 
        harm workers by paying them low wages, reducing their benefits, 
        and limiting their future employment opportunities;
            (21) nascent or potential rivals, even those that are 
        unprofitable or inefficient, are an important source of 
        competitive discipline for dominant firms;
            (22) antitrust enforcement against anticompetitive 
        exclusionary conduct has been impeded when courts have declined 
        to rigorously examine the facts in favor of relying on 
        inaccurate economic assumptions that are inconsistent with 
        contemporary economic learning, such as presuming that market 
        power is not durable and can be expected to self-correct, that 
        monopolies can drive as much or more innovation than a 
        competitive market, that above-cost pricing cannot harm 
        competition, and other flawed assumptions;
            (23) the courts of the United States have improperly 
        implied immunity from the antitrust laws based on Federal 
        regulatory statutes, even limiting the application of statutory 
        antitrust savings clauses passed by Congress;
            (24) the civil remedies currently available to cure 
        violations of the Sherman Antitrust Act, including injunctions, 
        equitable monetary relief, and private damages, have not proven 
        sufficient, on their own, to deter anticompetitive conduct;
            (25) in some cases, effective deterrence requires the 
        imposition of civil penalties, alone or in combination with 
        existing remedies, including structural relief, behavioral 
        relief, private damages, and equitable monetary relief, 
        including disgorgement and restitution; and
            (26) Federal antitrust enforcement budgets have failed to 
        keep pace with the growth of the economy and increasing demands 
        on agency resources, significantly undermining the ability of 
        the Federal antitrust agencies to fulfill their law enforcement 
        missions and contributing to the rise of market power in the 
        American economy.
    (b) Purposes.--The purposes of this Act are to--
            (1) enhance competition throughout the American economy by 
        strengthening antitrust enforcement by the Department of 
        Justice, the Federal Trade Commission, the State enforcement 
        agencies, and private parties;
            (2) revise the legal standard under section 7 of the 
        Clayton Act to better enable enforcers to arrest the likely 
        anticompetitive effects of harmful mergers in their incipiency, 
        as Congress intended, by clarifying that the potential effects 
        that may justify prohibiting a merger under the Clayton Act 
        include lower quality, reduced choice, reduced innovation, the 
        exclusion of competitors, or increased entry barriers, in 
        addition to increased price to buyers or reduced price to 
        sellers;
            (3) amend the Clayton Act to clarify that an acquisition 
        that tends to create a monopsony violates the Clayton Act;
            (4) establish simple, cost-effective decision rules that 
        require the parties to certain acquisitions that either 
        significantly increase concentration or are extremely large 
        bear the burden of establishing that the acquisition will not 
        materially harm competition;
            (5) prohibit and deter exclusionary conduct that harms 
        competition, particularly by dominant firms;
            (6) enable the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade 
        Commission to seek civil monetary penalties, in addition to 
        existing remedies, for violations of the Sherman Act;
            (7) give the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade 
        Commission additional financial resources and enforcement tools 
        to craft remedies for individual violations that are effective 
        to deter future unlawful conduct and proportionate to the 
        gravity of the violation;
            (8) provide further protections for those who provide 
        evidence of anticompetitive conduct to government enforcers and 
        potential financial rewards for whistleblowers who provide 
        information to the government that leads to a criminal fine; 
        and
            (9) grant successful antitrust plaintiffs the right to 
        obtain prejudgment interest on damages awards to further deter 
        anticompetitive conduct and increase compensation to injured 
        parties.

SEC. 3. DEFINITION.

    In this Act the term ``antitrust laws''--
            (1) has the meaning given that term in the first section of 
        the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. 12); and
            (2) includes--
                    (A) section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act 
                (15 U.S.C. 45) to the extent that such section applies 
                to unfair methods of competition; and
                    (B) this Act and the amendments made by this Act.

SEC. 4. UNLAWFUL ACQUISITIONS.

    (a) Market Power.--Subsection (a) of the first section of the 
Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. 12) is amended by adding at the end the 
following:
    ``The term `market power' in this Act means the ability of a 
person, or a group of persons acting in concert, to profitably impose 
terms or conditions on counterparties, including terms regarding price, 
quantity, product or service quality, or other terms affecting the 
value of consideration exchanged in the transaction, that are more 
favorable to the person or group of persons imposing them than what the 
person or group of persons could obtain in a competitive market.''.
    (b) Unlawful Acquisitions.--Section 7 of the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. 
18) is amended--
            (1) in the first and second undesignated paragraphs, by 
        striking ``substantially to lessen'' each place that term 
        appears and inserting ``to create an appreciable risk of 
        materially lessening'';
            (2) by inserting ``or a monopsony'' after ``monopoly'' each 
        place that term appears; and
            (3) by adding at the end the following:
    ``In a case brought by the United States, the Federal Trade 
Commission, or a State attorney general, a court shall determine that 
the effect of an acquisition described in this section may be to create 
an appreciable risk of materially lessening competition or to tend to 
create a monopoly or a monopsony, in or affecting commerce, if--
            ``(1) the acquisition would lead to a significant increase 
        in market concentration in any relevant market;
            ``(2) the acquisition would increase the ability and 
        incentive to engage in exclusionary conduct, as defined in 
        section 26A of the Clayton Act;
            ``(3)(A) the acquiring person has a market share of greater 
        than 50 percent or otherwise has significant market power, as a 
        seller or a buyer, in any relevant market, and as a result of 
        the acquisition, the acquiring person would obtain control over 
        entities or assets that compete or have a reasonable 
        probability of competing with the acquiring person in the same 
        relevant market; or
            ``(B) as a result of the acquisition, the acquiring person 
        would obtain control over entities or assets that have a market 
        share of greater than 50 percent or otherwise have significant 
        market power, as a seller or a buyer, in any relevant market, 
        and the acquiring person competes or has a reasonable 
        probability of competing with the entities or assets over which 
        it would obtain control, as a result of the acquisition, in the 
        same relevant market;
            ``(4) the acquisition would lead to the combination of 
        entities or assets that compete or have a reasonable 
        probability of competing in a relevant market, and either the 
        acquiring person or the entities or assets over which it would 
        obtain control prevents, limits, or disrupts coordinated 
        interaction among competitors in a relevant market or has a 
        reasonable probability of doing so;
            ``(5) the acquisition--
                    ``(A) would likely enable the acquiring person to 
                unilaterally and profitably exercise market power or 
                materially increase its ability to do so; or
                    ``(B) would materially increase the probability of 
                coordinated interaction among competitors in any 
                relevant market; or
            ``(6)(A) the acquisition is not a transaction that is 
        described in section 7A(c); and
            ``(B)(i) as a result of such acquisition, the acquiring 
        person would hold an aggregate total amount of the voting 
        securities and assets of the acquired person in excess of 
        $5,000,000,000 (as adjusted and published for each fiscal year 
        beginning after September 30, 2024, in the same manner as 
        provided in section 8(a)(5) to reflect the percentage change in 
        the gross national product for such fiscal year compared to the 
        gross national product for the year ending September 30, 2023; 
        or
            ``(ii)(I) the person acquiring or the person being acquired 
        has assets, net annual sales, or a market capitalization 
        greater than $100,000,000,000 (as so adjusted and published); 
        and
            ``(II) as a result of such acquisition, the acquiring 
        person would hold an aggregate total amount of the voting 
        securities and assets of the acquired person in excess of 
        $50,000,000 (as so adjusted and published), unless the 
        acquiring or acquired person establishes, by a preponderance of 
        the evidence, that the effect of the acquisition will not be to 
        create an appreciable risk of materially lessening competition 
        or will not tend to create a monopoly or a monopsony. In this 
        paragraph, the term `materially' means more than a de minimis 
        amount''.

SEC. 5. POST-PROCEEDING DATA.

    Section 7A of the Clayton Act (15 U.S.C. 18a) is amended by adding 
at the end the following:
    ``(l)(1) Each person who resolves a proceeding brought under the 
antitrust laws by the Federal Trade Commission or United States by 
entering into an agreement or by the final judgment in a Federal or 
administrative court regarding an acquisition with respect to which 
notification is required under this section shall, on an annual basis 
during the 5-year period beginning on the date on which the agreement 
is entered into, file with the Federal Trade Commission or the 
Assistant Attorney General, as applicable, and the Competition 
Advocate, information sufficient for the Federal Trade Commission or 
the United States, as applicable, to assess the competitive impact of 
the acquisition, including--
            ``(A) the pricing, availability, and quality of any product 
        or service, or inputs thereto, in any market, that was covered 
        by the agreement;
            ``(B) the source, and the resulting magnitude and extent, 
        of any cost-saving efficiencies or any benefits to consumers or 
        trading partners that were claimed as a benefit of the 
        acquisition and the extent to which any cost savings were 
        passed on to consumers or trading partners; and
            ``(C) the effectiveness of any divestitures or any 
        conditions placed on the acquisition in fully restoring 
        competition.
    ``(2) The requirement to provide the information described in 
paragraph (1) shall be included in an agreement described in that 
paragraph.
    ``(3) The Federal Trade Commission, with the concurrence of the 
Assistant Attorney General, by rule in accordance with section 553 of 
title 5, United States Code, and consistent with the purposes of this 
section--
            ``(A) shall require that the information described in 
        paragraph (1) be in such form and contain such documentary 
        material and information relevant to an acquisition as is 
        necessary and appropriate to enable the Federal Trade 
        Commission and the Assistant Attorney General to assess the 
        competitive impact of the acquisition under paragraph (1); and
            ``(B) may--
                    ``(i) define the terms used in this subsection;
                    ``(ii) exempt, from the requirements of this 
                section, information not relevant in assessing the 
                competitive impact of the acquisition under paragraph 
                (1); and
                    ``(iii) prescribe such other ru